Search This Blog

Wednesday, December 28, 2011

Coffee shops and the economy of the future.

Great little entry on ... Education, retail, and coffee shops

One scary thought: Maybe I should get out of the university game. If the bubble bursts, i would be about as relevant as a home builder in Florida. We all know that the price is highly inflated. We know technology is changing and that classroom style learning is kind of outdated. We know the product is becoming less attractive. Something has to give, right?

However, I do like the idea that retail, and offices may go towards this coffee shop model. Make things better for all. Offices and stores are not fun places to be.

Tuesday, December 27, 2011

Francis Fukyuama and New Ideologies

A new article by Francis Fukyuama in Foreign Affairs:

Fukyuama's main argument is that, in the West, the "left" has basically been defeated. Their main policy ideas are unaffordable, and incompatible with the growth that is required to pay for them. A return to social democracy is unlikely. Fukyuama is unhappy with this. He argues that a new alternative must arise so that economic liberalism has a challenger. In the U.S., the main political movement that has arisen in response to the Financial Crisis has been right-wing populism.

One of the most puzzling features of the world in the aftermath of the financial crisis is that so far, populism has taken primarily a right-wing form, not a left-wing one....In the United States, for example, although the Tea Party is anti-elitist in its rhetoric, its members vote for conservative politicians who serve the interests of precisely those financiers and corporate elites they claim to despise.

Ultimately, he argues, it is democracy that is at stake.

AM: One has to agree that the political influence of financeers has unsettling implications for democracy. But the answer to this may be more capitalism, not less. Perhaps this is the new ideology? One that would seek to separate government influence from the market, and vice versa, through a reduction in the size and scope of government and employing market mechanisms, like competition and choice, as a way to curb corporate excess.

Caption contest

Real Johnson caption contest, takes shots at parallel polity readers!

Wednesday, December 14, 2011

A bubble means that you’re not as rich as you think you are: the case of education

Prices are how activities are coordinated, and sometimes, due to government interference price signals are wrong. Nowhere is this becoming more apparent than the realm of higher education. It’s pretty evident: education costs have skyrocketed in recent years at a level that far outpaces the CPI.



(from Carpe Diem)

The parallels with housing are striking. In the case of housing, government policy wanted to promote home ownership. In this case, government policy is to promote higher education. The mechanisms were also similar: the U.S. government (and Canadian provinces) expanded credit by subsidizing student loans and tuition. Low interest rates under the Greenspan years also made borrowing easier. The result, it’s easier to afford school.

Well intentioned? Yes. More people get university educations, and that’s good, right? Maybe. I’m sceptical. But there are some serious downsides: first, the degree costs more and is worth less. Second, the high demand has resulted in even higher prices. Cheap credit allows everyone to play, but when everyone plays, the price rises, and the ‘signalling value’ decrease. Who wins? The universities that reap the benefits of high tuition costs and skyrocketing demand. Who loses? The students: they overvalue the degree: too many people go to school. If you’re one of those people the reality is you’re not as rich as you think you are. Education is an investment. Students made what you think is a solid investment in school with the expectation of some future payoff and then realize when they test the market that they may have to accept a lower paying job or no job at all in their field. When the interest rates on student debt rise, the emerging graduates feel a little bit more like they’ve been ripped off: the actual cost of the degree (not to mention the opportunity cost) was a little bit more than it was worth. In short, you’re not quite as rich as you thought you were. Devalued human capital makes up the slack.

What about on the supply side? The artificially high price of education leads to further misallocation of resources: too many ‘resources’ are sucked into the education sphere. Universities are expanding based on these price signals. They are making commitments, investments etc… If the bubble bursts maybe some people are not going to get paid. Just like housing. Now the big question is: will the bubble burst? Obviously I don’t know. Since government student loan programs can keep hammering out cheap credit forever, this bubble may continue for a long time. But there are other factors: maybe employers may place less value on university as a signalling model. This makes sense because North American universities are turning out some pretty bad grads. Third, a major technological change in the way that affects how education is delivered might totally mess things up.

Another weird parallel is with gov. response to bad investments. In housing, creditors and
bankers received the now infamous bailouts. What about educational malinvestments? That’s really what the OWS movement was a calling for on this one… investor bailouts: the investor in this case: the beleaguered women’s studies grad.


Read more

Tuesday, December 13, 2011

The Failure of Climate Talks...




Smart comment from the Globe and Mail's Margaret Wente:

The key thing to understand about the climate talks is that they’re not really about the climate. They’re about power and money. They are about the desire of fast-growing emitters such as Brazil, South Africa, India and China to extract billions in so-called climate reparations from rich countries, especially the United States. These and other so-called developing countries now account for more than half of greenhouse gas emissions. They want the rich countries to start cutting large amounts of carbon right away, while they do nothing. The rich countries are understandably reluctant. Hence the impasse.

AM: We here at Parallel Polity are not climate change deniers. It's a real problem. But as a political scientist, it's quite obvious the large-scale international agreements are not the way to go. The barriers to successful negotiation are huge; power political always rules over the technocratic; and when rules are made, there is no guarantee that they will be implemented or followed.

Furthermore, it also seems that the world focuses too much on the issue of emission reduction. Are we even sure that this is going to have any real effect? How much do we have to cut to make any dent? Why not invest more in new technological solutions like geoengineering, which might be way cheaper and although still unproven, potentially more effective?

Forecasting, weather, and economy

This is great! From the Ottawa Citizen...

Two top U.S. hurricane forecasters, revered like rock stars in Deep South hurricane country, are quitting the practice because it doesn’t work.

William Gray and Phil Klotzbach say a look back shows their past 20 years of forecasts had no value.


These guys clearly have their professional integrity. Now, if we could just get macroeconomic forecasters to quit their jobs.... It's really the same basic problem: using abstract models to predict complex events in a contingent world. And they perform terribly as well. Economists know this, but I think they continue b/c people ask for their advice. See Steve Levitt on this....

Monday, December 12, 2011

Unintended Consequences: Doo-gooders and Housing Bubbles


In my last post, I referred to the work of economists who argue that government policy was the cause of the housing bubble and the financial crisis. (I’ll stick with the housing bubble here, because even though they are related, they are separate issues). I often emphasize this point, not just because it is always overlooked in discussions of this issue, the economy, and the future, but because it pisses off my lefty friends who will take any excuse they can to bash free-market capitalism.

In response to my last post, fellow blogger the Real Johnson, comments: “The government didn’t just decide, ‘’hey, poor people should be able to own houses too.’” In this post, i'd like to address this point. In my view, there was a coherent policy, and it was basically well-intentioned.

I think the mechanics of the government-failure argument are pretty sound. I won’t rehash them, but you can read good overviews here, and here. When presented with this point, people often respond by trying to save the “evil capitalism” narrative as follows: it was the evil companies that corrupted government to put these policies in place so that they could make money. Now, let me say right away: I’m not fundamentally against this type of argument. There is far too much money and influence from corporations and special interest in politics, in my opinion. I don’t know of anyone who disagrees with this basic, albeit vague principle.

The question is, in this instance, which special interests and political forces were driving federal government housing policy? Was there even a policy to begin with? And if there was, were the designers intending to help poor people? The answer to the last two questions is “yes.”

The policy is clear. Bill Clinton announced his “Home Ownership Strategy” in 1995. It tries to make a case for homeownership based largely on positive externalities (economic development, dignity, financial stability crime etc…) and on inequality (fairness). Indeed, the touted benefits of the policy were: help poor people, help the community. How was the ownership strategy carried out? First, Fanny and Freddy were required to buy mortgages made to low-income buyers. Congress leaned on them heavily. Second, to make investment and ownership more attractive, tax policy was changed so that capital gains from housing were treated differently than others. Third, state restrictions on commercial lending that prevented banks from taking recourse against defaulters. Fourth, the implementation of tax deductions for mortgages. Clearly, there was a coherent policy at work. It wasn’t “deregulation” but an agenda to increase homeownership.

The second part of the issue concerns the “political economy” of housing policy. What political forces were behind this? This is a little bit more difficult to answer: but there is reason to believe that it was the forces of good, not so much the forces of evil. One lobby that pushed for cheap housing was ACORN: as early as 1992 they were pressuring banks to issue mortgage loans to (poor) people who did not qualify.
From the NY Times:

Prodded by Federal laws and an aggressive community-action group called Acorn, banks here and in other cities across the country have started making mortgage loans in neighborhoods they have traditionally avoided.
The article goes on to say:

A Federal regulator concurs. "Acorn is street-tough rough and they bedevil the bankers," he said. "But they've gotten banks to commit millions they otherwise would not have lent."
This cause was picked up by members of the Democratic Party, and pushed the center of the agenda under Clinton, and then again under Bush. Barney Frank’s role in this is well documented
He continues to deny that home-ownership policies had anything to do with the crisis, but this betrays a sort of cognitive dissonance, or a basic misunderstanding of the fundamentals (he says that home owners were not highly leveraged: but three percent down = highly leveraged). As late as 2005, he says in speech to Congress that the housing bubble is essential fake (not a bubble) and that he and his Committee would continue to push for home ownership.

This is not to say that leftwing doo-gooders were fully responsible for the housing bubble: only to say that it was caused by government policy and that it was basically well intentioned. Not many people saw this coming. Very few of the ones that did would estimate the cascading effects on the rest of the financial system and economy. But really, when housing prices are rising it’s hard to argue that everyone shouldn’t buy in. I speculate that those on the right were probably complicit in their acceptance of these policies. Indeed, if anything, homeownership and housing prices continued to rise thanks to continuation of Clinton-era policies by the Bush administration. So this is not entirely a ‘left-right’ thing, but clearly the driving force was government policy, and the intention was basically good.

In the end, IMO, the lesson is unintended consequences of government intervention. Lots of well-meaning policies have bad outcomes. This is the basic problem: knowledge. You don’t know, in advance, how people are going to react. This isn’t about science: economics is not that.

Friday, December 9, 2011

Cautionary Examples

Apparently libertarianism is incompatible with white supremacy (I guess "White racial nationalism" is the PC term these days). To be honest, as a classical liberal, I'd be disappointed with any other conclusion.

Thus, for today's "Cautionary example" installment you can read an incoherent, racist diatribe masquerading as scholarship essay explaining why, from the point of view of a neo-nazi white supremacist, er... "white racial nationalist."

Most of their beef is with open immigration. Apparently the minimal state is not optimal for protecting the purity of the white race. After skimming some of the nonsensical ramblings arguments (apparently libertarians are mostly Jews that support both polygamy and slavery), I turned to the references. About two thirds of the footnotes refer to the work of a Dr. Kevin MacDonald, who just happens to be the author. That's fine scholarship, even for a reputable periodical like the "Journal for Occidental Studies."

Newt and the Crisis



Russ Roberts on why Gingrich is kind of scary.

First, they are for Freddie Mac who paid him something around $1.6 million for his “services.” He described this work originally as being payment for his historical knowledge of housing. Cue laughter, folks. This interview gives you a glimpse of the real reason he was hired. He was hired, of course, to provide cover for Freddie Mac.

Because they were thought to had an implicit guarantee of government support, they were able to issue bonds at relatively low rates of interest. They were very eager to use that money to buy more mortgages. The problem was that because of that implicit guarantee, they were constrained by regulation to only buy fairly safe mortgages with 20% downpayments. Starting in the mid-1990′s, Clinton (and then Bush) required them to relax their standards. They didn’t end up buying a lot of sub-prime, just a lot of low down-payment mortgages that were very prone to end up underwater if housing prices ever fell. This injection of credit into the market pushed up the price of housing (starting around 1995) launched the housing bubble and along with other government programs, helped make speculative subprime lending.


AM: Russ Roberts really knows a lot about this issue. (Check out his essay: Other people's money) He really does a good job of laying out exactly how these entities caused the housing bubble. It wasn't really through sub-prime lending. They were exposed to this, but not that much. It was the low-downpayment mortgages, and the expansion of credit. And, it was political. It wasn't just greed from lenders or investors: it was a government policy to give houses to poor people. That's a fact. All of the people who talk about failures of capitalism and deregulation miss this fundamental point. it was a policy, and the policy makers had good intentions.

Thursday, December 8, 2011

More on bias and honesty

Smart essay from Econlog Blogger Arnold Kling:

Political disagreement can be explained using the theories of cognitive hubris and radical ignorance. The basic idea is that nobody has a grasp on capital-T truth, but each of us believes that our own map of the world is highly accurate. When we encounter someone who holds a similar map, we think, “That guy knows what he is talking about.” When we encounter someone who holds a different map, we think, “That guy is an idiot.” When you overestimate the accuracy of your own map, it is very difficult to explain the existence of people with different maps, other than to impugn their intelligence or their integrity.

AM: Remember this when you're calling someone in an opposite political camp "an idiot." Karl Popper said, referring to our knowledge of the social world, that "social scientists drive their piles in swamps." There is ground but it is soft and constantly shifting.

I tell my students, when they are doing 'readings' to operate under the assumption that the author is honest, smart, and trying to make a real contribution to a subject. This certainly does not mean that one is forced to agree with the author, criticism is always encouraged. But I think honesty requires giving your intellectual foil the benefit of the doubt. This is one reason why I appreciate Kling's point about cognitive bias: we are none of us immune, but we can try to move forward if we recognize this.

This is also what I was trying to get at with the post on Maher.

Bill Maher kinda sucks now...


I used to be a fan of Bill Maher. His talk shows were funny; his movie was great. He dumped on religion and advocated for drug legalization. His politically-oriented comedy was always thoughtful. But not so much anymore. Having watched the last season of Real time, it is clear to me that Maher is degenerating into a partisan hack. He’s so committed more to bashing conservatives and defending democrats that he has a hard time being either smart or funny. While he usually has interesting guests, he often ruins the conversation through his constant political pandering.

A little political pandering is good when you get two member of the Tea Party on the panel. But it totally breaks down when Maher brings in people with more nuanced views. The last episode I saw featured Times columnist and legendary blogger Andrew Sullivan. Sullivan is a pretty smart guy, not obviously partisan on either side, and has clearly thought about many different issues. When he tried to point out to Maher that the debate over tax policy was not simply about ‘higher taxes or lower taxes’, but about various types of tax reform, Maher said, “stop trying to be a conservative.” End of discussion. Earlier in the year, when libertarian thinker and reason TV editor Nick Gellispie showed up to talk about his new book, he pretty much spent the whole time trying to convince Maher that he was not a Republican. When Bloomberg was on, and pointed out that government policy (through Fanny and Freddy) played a role in the financial crisis, Maher was at a loss. It’s surprising to hear this. It’s not like he’s a foaming-at-the mouth conservative, Maher remarked.

You see, that’s the problem. The world is nuanced. But the world of political parties is not. Rep’s and Dem’s are black and white. If you are too much of a hack, this prism obscures all reasonable debate. Gray area is literally non-existent. Comedy is also nuanced. Most politicians are not (intentionally) funny.

As a guy who is so dissatisfied with the American political system, it’s odd that Maher doesn’t realize that the problem is actually political polarization. When you take the view that all conservatives are idiots, and that’s the problem, then you’re really part of the problem yourself. That’s why Jon Stewart is far better. He’s not a black and white guy. He’s a democrat, but he treats many of his rivals (like O’Reilly) with a little respect. As a result, his show is a little more honest, and his comedy is a little better. That’s the sad thing here. Maher is supposed to be a comedian and an entertainer. But lately, his shit just sounds tired, I don’t learn much, and I don’t laugh.

Tuesday, December 6, 2011

The Arab Winter


Daniel Byman makes a pessimistic forecast for the Arab Winter:


The most dangerous outcome of the Arab Winter, however, is the spread of chaos and violence. In Syria, where thousands have already died, the body count may grow exponentially as sectarian killings spread and peaceful protesters take up arms. In Yemen, the resignation of Ali Abdullah Saleh has not ended the turmoil throughout the country. And Libya, lacking strong institutions and divided by tribal and political factions, may never get its new government off the ground.

AM: Byman rightly highlights some facts that may be unpleasant for supporters of democracy. First, dictators and strongmen sometimes do a better job of maintaining order and peace within weak states. For example: the removal of Hussein in Iraq unleashed massive sectarian violence. This does not mean that democracy is not a laudable long term goal, only that it may not be the best system for government for weak states which face problems consolidating political order.
Second, democratic governance may not mean more 'peace' between countries. For example, should radical organizations come to gain control over the Egyptian or Jordian governments, Byman notes, this could lead to a deterioration in relations with Israel.

Saturday, December 3, 2011

Don't let the Fox Guard the Hen House...




AM: Smart little blurb from GMU's Christopher Coyne. I quite like this analogy. Do you really want the fox guarding the hen house?

Friday, December 2, 2011

Thoughts on the Attawapiskat issue



Attawapiskat is a pretty big story these days. I don’t really know much about the underlying issues, but just some random thoughts. Obviously it’s a travesty that we have this level of poverty and neglect in Canada. It’s even worse that the government took so long to respond at all to this emergency. I find the political discourse on this issue is pretty disappointing. The government has managed to spin this issue to their advantage by asking: “where’s the money”? Essentially, they have managed to convince people that this is just a case of mismanagement of money. Honestly, I really have no idea of the federal funds were mismanaged, (this is good analysis) but even if they were, it’s hardly the real issue. Several points to consider:

(a) This is not an isolated incident.
(b) Canadians don’t seem to think it’s an important issue. It pops up every now and then … but Canadian’s are generally happy to ignore the north, and I think the “where’s the money” story is popular because it’s the path of least resistance.
(c) There are certainly issues about the long term viability of Northern Communities that are real. Canada is locked into certain orthodoxies about economic development models for these communities that don’t seem to work. Obviously the “why are they living there” argument is too narrow - first nations communities closer to urban areas also suffer some of these problems.
(d) Is it too obvious to say that First Nation’s communities need a sustainable economic base, and they need better governance structures. Probably… how do you get there? No f’ing clue.

This post is a pretty good summary. I think it may overstate the control that INAC actually has over federal transfers – one line of the Indian Act doesn’t really prove anything about how programs are actually managed. But other than that, good set information.
(HT: MB)

Thursday, December 1, 2011

Three inconvenient truths for OWS

Three inconvenient truths for OWS:



Restates the points I made about in an earlier post about immigration and households and inequality, but much or eloquently.